Option Pricing Functions to Accompany *Derivatives Markets*

rm(list=ls())
library(highlight)
library(knitr)
library(ggplot2)
library(dplyr)
library(tidyr)
##homedir <- '/home/rmcd/tex/d67/Rtutorial/'
options(digits=4)
figsize <- 4.5
opts_chunk$set(size='footnotesize', prompt=FALSE, comment=NA,
               fig.align='center', fig.width = figsize,
               fig.height=figsize, out.width='3.75in')
opts_knit$set(highlight = TRUE,
              eval.after='fig.cap',
              prompt=TRUE,
              renderer=renderer_latex(document=FALSE),
              size='footnotesize')
curr <- function(amt)  formatC(amt, format='f', digits=2)
library(derivmkts)
library(mnormt)
library(markdown)

opts_chunk$set(collapse=TRUE)

Introduction

This vignette is an overview to the functions in the derivmkts package, which was conceived as a companion to my book Derivatives Markets @mcdonald:derivs:13. The material has an educational focus. There are other option pricing packages for R, but this package has several distinguishing features:

Pricing functions and greeks

European Calls and Puts

Table \ref{tab:bslist} lists the Black-Scholes related functions in the package.^[See @black/scholes:73 and @merton:73-bell.] The functions bscall, bsput, and bsopt provide basic pricing of European calls and puts. There are also options with binary payoffs: cash-or-nothing and asset-or-nothing options. All of these functions are vectorized. The function bsopt by default provides option greeks. Here are some examples:

s <- 100; k <- 100; r <- 0.08; v <- 0.30; tt <- 2; d <- 0
bscall(s, k, v, r, tt, d)
bsput(s, c(95, 100, 105), v, r, tt, d)

\begin{table}[tp] \centering \begin{tabular}{cp{4in}} Function& Description \ \hline bscall & European call\ bsput & European put\ bsopt & European call and put and associated Greeks: delta, gamma, vega, theta, rho, psi, and elasticity \ assetcall & Asset-or-nothing call\ assetput & Asset-or-nothing put\ cashcall & Cash-or-nothing call\ cashput & Cash-or-nothing put \end{tabular} \caption{Black-Scholes related option pricing functions} \label{tab:bslist} \end{table}

Barrier Options

There are pricing functions for the following barrier options:^[See @merton:73-bell, p. 175, for the first derivation of a barrier option pricing formula and @mcdonald:derivs:13, Chapter 14, for an overview.]

Naming for the barrier options generally follows the convention

[u|d][i|o][call|put]

which means that the option is up'' ordown'', in'' orout'', and a call or put.^[This naming convention differs from that in @mcdonald:derivs:13, in which names are callupin, callupout, etc. Thus, I have made both names available for these functions.] An up-and-in call, for example, would be denoted by uicall. For binary options, we add the underlying, which is either the asset or \$1: cash:

[asset|cash][u|d][i|o][call|put]
H <- 115
bscall(s, c(80, 100, 120), v, r, tt, d)
## Up-and-in call
uicall(s, c(80, 100, 120), v, r, tt, d, H)
bsput(s, c(80, 100, 120), v, r, tt, d)
## Up-and-out put
uoput(s, c(80, 100, 120), v, r, tt, d, H)

Perpetual American Options

The functions callperpetual and putperetual price infinitely-lived American options.^[@merton:73-bell derived the price of a perpetual American put.] The pricing formula assumes that all inputs (risk-free rate, volatility, dividend yield) are fixed. This is of course usual with the basic option pricing formulas, but it is more of a conceptual stretch for an infinitely-lived option than for a 3-month option.

In order for the option to have a determined value, the dividend yield on the underlying asset must be positive if the option is a call. If this is not true, the call is never exercised and the price is undefined.^[A well-known result (see @merton:73-bell) is that a standard American call is never exercised before expiration if the dividend yield is zero and the interest rate is non-negative. A perpetual call with $\delta=0$ and $r>0$ would thus never be exercised. The limit of the option price as $\delta\to 0$ is $s$, so in this case the function returns the stock price as the option value.] Similarly, the risk-free rate must be positive if the option is a put.

By default, the perpetual pricing formulas return the price. By setting showbarrier=TRUE, the function returns both the option price and the stock price at which the option is optimally exercised (the ``barrier''). Here are some examples:

s <- 100; k <- 100; r <- 0.08; v <- 0.30; tt <- 2; d <- 0.04
callperpetual(s, c(95, 100, 105), v, r, d)
callperpetual(s, c(95, 100, 105), v, r, d, showbarrier=TRUE)

Option Greeks

Options greeks are mathematical derivatives of the option price with respect to inputs; see @mcdonald:derivs:13, Chapters 12 and 13, for a discussion of the greeks for vanilla options. Greeks for vanilla and barrier options can be computed using the greeks function, which is a wrapper for any pricing function that returns the option price and which uses the default naming of inputs.^[In this version of the package, I have two alternative functions that return Greeks:

These may be deprecated in the future. greeks2 is more cumbersome to use but may be more robust. I welcome feedback on these functions and what you find useful. ]

H <- 105
greeks(uicall(s, k, v, r, tt, d, H))

The value of this approach is that you can easily compute Greeks for spreads and custom pricing functions. Here are two examples. First, the value at time 0 of a prepaid contract that pays $S_{T}^{a}$ at time $T$ is given by the powercontract() function:

powercontract <- function(s, v, r, tt, d, a) {
    price <- exp(-r*tt)*s^a* exp((a*(r-d) + 1/2*a*(a-1)*v^2)*tt)
}

We can easily compute the Greeks for a power contract:

greeks(powercontract(s=40, v=.08, r=0.08, tt=0.25, d=0, a=2))

Second, consider a bull spread in which we buy a call with a strike of $k_{1}$ and sell a call with a strike of $k_2$. We can create a function that computes the value of the spread, and then compute the greeks for the spread by using this newly-created function together with greeks():

bullspread <- function(s, v, r, tt, d, k1, k2) {
    bscall(s, k1, v, r, tt, d) - bscall(s, k2, v, r, tt, d)
}
greeks(bullspread(39:41, .3, .08, 1, 0, k1=40, k2=45))

The Greeks function is vectorized, so you can create vectors of greek values with a single call. This example plots, for a bull spread, the gamma as a function of the stock price; see Figure \ref{fig:bullgamma}.

sseq <- seq(1, 100, by=0.5)
greeks(bullspread(sseq, .3, .08, 1, 0, k1=40, k2=45),
            initcaps = TRUE, long = TRUE) %>%
    filter(greek == 'Gamma' ) %>% 
    ggplot(aes(x = s, y = value)) + geom_line()

This code produces the plots in Figure \ref{fig:allgreeks}:

k <- 100; r <- 0.08; v <- 0.30; tt <- 2; d <- 0
S <- seq(.5, 200, by=.5)
Call <- greeks(bscall(S, k, v, r, tt, d), long = TRUE)
Put <- greeks(bsput(S, k, v, r, tt, d), long = TRUE)
ggplot(rbind(Call, Put), aes(x = s, y = value, color = funcname )) +
    geom_line() + facet_wrap(~ greek, scales = 'free_y') +
    scale_color_discrete(name = 'Option', labels = c('Call','Put' )) +
    scale_x_continuous('Stock', breaks =c(0, 100, 200)  ) +
    scale_y_continuous('Value') 

Binomial Pricing of European and American Options

There are two functions related to binomial option pricing:^[See @cox/ross/rubinstein:79, @rendleman/bartter:79-jf, and @mcdonald:derivs:13, Chapter 11]

Here are examples of pricing, illustrating the default of just returning the price, and the ability to return the price plus parameters, as well as the price, the parameters, and various trees:

s <- 100; k <- 100; r <- 0.08; v <- 0.30; tt <- 2; d <- 0.03
binomopt(s, k, v, r, tt, d, nstep=3)
binomopt(s, k, v, r, tt, d, nstep=3, returnparams=TRUE)
binomopt(s, k, v, r, tt, d, nstep=3, putopt=TRUE)
binomopt(s, k, v, r, tt, d, nstep=3, returntrees=TRUE, putopt=TRUE)

Asian Options

There are analytical functions for valuing geometric Asian options and Monte Carlo routines for valuing arithmetic Asian options.^[See @kemna/vorst:90.] Be aware that the greeks() function at this time will not work with the Monte Carlo valuation for arithmetic Asian options. I plan to address this in a future release.^[As the functions are currently written, each invocation of the pricing function will start with a different random number seed, resulting in price variation that is due solely to random variation. Moreover, random number generation changes the random number seed globally. In a future release I hope to address this by saving and restoring the seed within the greeks function. For the curious, a Stackoverflow post discusses this issue.]

Geometric Asian Options

Geometric Asian options can be valued using the Black-Scholes formulas for vanilla calls and puts, with modified inputs. The functions return both call and put prices with a named vector:

s <- 100; k <- 100; r <- 0.08; v <- 0.30; tt <- 2; d <- 0.03; m <- 3
geomavgpricecall(s, 98:102, v, r, tt, d, m)
geomavgpricecall(s, 98:102, v, r, tt, d, m, cont=TRUE)
geomavgstrikecall(s, k, v, r, tt, d, m)

Arithmetic Asian Options

Monte Carlo valuation is used to price arithmetic Asian options. For efficiency, the function arithasianmc returns call and put prices for average price and average strike options. By default the number of simulations is 1000. Optionally the function returns the standard deviation of each estimate

arithasianmc(s, k, v, r, tt, d, 3, numsim=5000, printsds=TRUE)

The function arithavgpricecv uses the control variate method to reduce the variance in the simulation. At the moment this function prices only calls, and returns both the price and the regression coefficient used in the control variate correction:

arithavgpricecv(s, k, v, r, tt, d, 3, numsim=5000)

Compound Options

A compound option is an option where the underlying asset is an option.^[See @geske:79 and @mcdonald:derivs:13, Chapter 14.] The terminology associated with compound options can be confusing, so it may be easiest to start with an example.

Figure \ref{fig:compoundopt} is a timeline for a compound option that is an option to buy a put. The compound option expires at $t_{1}$ and the put expires at $t_{2}$. The owner of the compound option only acquires the put if at time $t_{1}$ it is worth at least $k_{co}$, and only exercises the put if at time $t_{2}$ the stock price is less than $k_{uo}$.

\begin{figure} \centering \begin{tikzpicture} \newcommand{\start}{0} \newcommand{\finish}{9} \newcommand{\midpt}{(\finish/2-\start/2} \newcommand{\tickheight}{0.3} \draw (\start,0) -- (\finish,0); \draw (0,\tickheight) -- (0, -\tickheight) node[below] {\begin{tabular}{c} Time 0 \ Buy compound option \end{tabular}}; \draw (\midpt,\tickheight) -- (\midpt, -\tickheight) node[below] {\begin{tabular}{c} Time $t_{1}$ \ Compound exercise decision \ Pay $k_{co}$ to buy put? \end{tabular} }; \draw (\finish, \tickheight) -- (\finish, -\tickheight) node[below] { \begin{tabular}{c} Time $t_{2}$ \ Put exercise decision\ Sell stock for $k_{uo}$? \end{tabular} }; \end{tikzpicture} \caption{The timeline for a compound option: a call to buy a put. The compound option expires at time $t_{1}$ and the underlying asset is a put option that expires at time $t_{2}$. At time $t_{1}$, the owner decides whether to pay $k_{co}$ to buy a put option which has time to expiration $t_{2} - t_{1}$. At time $t_{2}$ the owner decides whether to exercise the put, selling the stock for the strike price of $k_{uo}$.} \label{fig:compoundopt} \end{figure}

Definition of a Compound Option

Based on the example, you can see that there are three prices associated with a compound option:

The definition of a compound option therefore requires that we specify

Given these possibilities, you can have a call on a call, a put on a call, a call on a put, and a put on a put. The valuation procedure require calculating the underlying asset price at which you are indifferent about acquiring the underlying option.

The price calculation requires computing the stock price above or below which you would optimally exercise the option at time $t_{1}$.

Examples

As an example, consider the following inputs for a call option to buy a call option:

s <- 100; kuo <- 95; v <- 0.30; r <-  0.08; t1 <- 0.50; t2 <- 0.75; d <- 0
kco <- 3.50

calloncall(s, kuo, kco, v, r, t1, t2, d, returnscritical=TRUE)

With these parameters, after 6 months ($t_{1}=0.5$), the compound option buyer decides whether to pay \$r formatC(kco, format='f', digits=2) to acquire a 3-month call on the underlying asset. (The volatility of the underlying asset is r v.) It will be worthwhile to pay the compound strike, \$r curr(kco), as long as the underlying asset price exceeds r calloncall(s, kuo, kco, v, r, t1, t2, d, returnscritical=TRUE)['scritical'].

Similarly, there is a put on the call, and a call and put on the corresponding put:

putoncall(s, kuo, kco, v, r, t1, t2, d, returnscritical=TRUE)
callonput(s, kuo, kco, v, r, t1, t2, d, returnscritical=TRUE)
putonput(s, kuo, kco, v, r, t1, t2, d, returnscritical=TRUE)

Jumps and Stochastic Volatility

\label{sec:jumps}

The mertonjump function returns call and put prices for a stock that can jump discretely.^[See @merton/jfe/1976.] A poisson process controls the occurrence of a jump and the size of the jump is lognormally distributed. The parameter lambda is the mean number of jumps per year, the parameter alphaj is the log of the expected jump, and sigmaj is the standard deviation of the log of the jump. The jump amount is thus drawn from the distribution \begin{equation} Y \sim \mathcal{N}(\alpha_{J} - 0.5\sigma^{2}{J}, \sigma{J}^{2} ) \end{equation}

mertonjump(s, k, v, r, tt, d, lambda=0.5, alphaj=-0.2, vj=0.3)
c(bscall(s, k, v, r, tt, d), bsput(s, k, v, r, tt, d))

Bonds

The simple bond functions provided in this version compute the present value of cash flows (bondpv), the IRR of the bond (bondyield), Macaulay duration (duration), and convexity (convexity).

coupon <- 8; mat <- 20; yield <- 0.06; principal <- 100; 
modified <- FALSE; freq <- 2
price <- bondpv(coupon, mat, yield, principal, freq)
price
bondyield(price, coupon, mat, principal, freq)
duration(price, coupon, mat, principal, freq, modified)
convexity(price, coupon, mat, principal, freq)

Monte Carlo simulation of prices

The function simprice provides a flexible way to generate prices that can be used for Monte Carlo valuation or just to illustrate sample paths. This function implements "naive" Monte Carlo, not making use of any variance reduction techniques. When supplied with a covariance matrix, simprice produces correlated asset prices. For more information on Monte Carlo see @mcdonald:derivs:13, Chapter 19, and @glasserman:mc:04, especially Chapter 4.

Simulated price paths

A simple example is to generate 5 random sample paths of daily stock prices for a year; see Figure \ref{fig:fivepaths}:

s0 <- 100; v <- 0.3; r <- 0.10; d <- 0; tt <- 1
trials <- 5; periods <- 365; set.seed(1)
s <- simprice(s0 = s0, v = v, r = r, tt = tt, d = d, trials = trials,
              periods = periods, jump = FALSE, long = TRUE)
ggplot(s, aes(x = period, y = price, color = trial, group = trial)) + geom_line()

We can do the same exercise adding jumps; see Figure \ref{fig:fivejumpers}.

s0 <- 100; v <- 0.3; r <- 0.10; d <- 0; tt <- 1
trials <- 5; periods <- 365; jump <- TRUE; lambda <- 2;
alphaj <- -0.1; vj <- 0.2; set.seed(1)
s <- simprice(s0 = s0, v = v, r = r, tt = tt, d = d, trials = trials,
              periods = periods, jump = jump, alphaj = alphaj,
              lambda = lambda, vj = vj, long = TRUE)
ggplot(s, aes(x = period, y = price, color = trial, group = trial)) + geom_line()

\newpage

Multiple correlated stocks

Here is an example using a three-asset covariance matrix, showing that the simulated series have the correct variance structure. We have three correlated stocks with standard deviations of 60%, 20%, and 45%., with the covariance matrix given by v. Compare the estimated covariance matrix with v:

set.seed(1)
vi <- diag(3)
tt <- 2; periods <- tt*365
diag(vi) <- c(.6, .2, .45)
vc <- matrix(c(1, .4, -.3,
              .4, 1, .25,
              -.3, .25, 1), nrow = 3) 
v <- vi %*% vc %*% vi
s <- simprice(s0 = s0, v = v, r = r, tt = tt, d = d, trials = 1,
              periods = periods, jump = FALSE, long = TRUE)

threestocks <- s %>%
    filter(trial == 1) %>%
    group_by(asset) %>%
    mutate(ret = log(price/lag(price)),
           row = row_number()) %>%
    select(asset, period, ret) %>%
    spread(key = asset, value = ret )

var(threestocks[2:4], na.rm = TRUE)*365
v

Functions with Graphical Output

Several functions provide visual illustrations of some aspects of the material.

Quincunx or Galton Board

The quincunx is a physical device the illustrates the central limit theorem. A ball rolls down a pegboard and strikes a peg, falling randomly either to the left or right. As it continues down the board it continues to strike a series of pegs, randomly falling left or right at each. The balls collect in bins and create an approximate normal distribution.

The quincunx function allows the user to simulate a quincunx, observing the path of each ball and watching the height of each bin as the balls accumulate. More interestingly, the quincunx function permits altering the probability that the ball will fall to the right.

Figure \ref{fig:quincunx} illustrates the function after dropping 200 balls down 20 levels of pegs with a 70\% probability that each ball will fall right:

par(mar=c(2,2,2,2))
quincunx(n=20, numballs=200, delay=0, probright=0.7)

Plotting the Solution to the Binomial Pricing Model

\label{sec:binomplot}

The binomplot function calls binomopt to compute the option price and the various trees, which it then uses in plotting:

The first plot, figure \ref{fig:binomplot1}, is basic:

s0 <- 100; k <- 100; v <- 0.3; r <- 0.08; tt <- 2; d <- 0
binomplot(s0, k, v, r, tt, d, nstep=6, american=TRUE, putopt=TRUE)

The second plot, figure \ref{fig:binomplot2}, adds a display of stock prices and arrows connecting the nodes.

```r except that values and arrows are added to the plot.'} binomplot(s0, k, v, r, tt, d, nstep=6, american=TRUE, putopt=TRUE, plotvalues=TRUE, plotarrows=TRUE)

As a final example, consider an American call when the dividend yield
is positive and `nstep` has a larger value. Figure
\ref{fig:binomplot3} shows the plot, with early exercise evident.

```r
d <- 0.06
binomplot(s0, k, v, r, tt, d, nstep=40, american=TRUE)

The large value of nstep creates a high maximum terminal stock price, which makes details hard to discern in the boundary region where exercise first occurrs. We can zoom in on that region by selecting values for ylimval; the result is in Figure \ref{fig:binomplot4}.

d <- 0.06
binomplot(s0, k, v, r, tt, d, nstep=40, american=TRUE, ylimval=c(75, 225))

References



Try the derivmkts package in your browser

Any scripts or data that you put into this service are public.

derivmkts documentation built on June 6, 2019, 5:03 p.m.