knitr::opts_chunk$set(echo = TRUE, message = FALSE, warning = FALSE, widtht = 65) options(width = 65)
The formula-data interface is a critical advantage of the R
software. It provides a practical way to describe the model to be
estimated and to store data. However, the usual interface is not
flexible enough to deal correctly with random utility
models. Therefore, mlogit
provides tools to construct richer
data.frame
s and formula
s.
mlogit
is loaded using:
library("mlogit")
It comes with several data sets that we'll use to illustrate the features of the library. Data sets used for multinomial logit estimation concern some individuals, that make one or a sequential choice of one alternative among a set of mutually exclusive alternatives. The determinants of these choices are covariates that can depend on the alternative and the choice situation, only on the alternative or only on the choice situation.
To illustrate this typology of the covariates, consider the case of repeated choice of destinations for vacations by families:
The unit of observation is therefore the choice situation, and it is also the individual if there is only one choice situation per individual observed, which is often the case.
Such data have therefore a specific structure that can be
characterized by three indexes: the alternative, the choice situation
and the individual. These three indexes will be denoted alt
, chid
and id
. Note that the distinction between chid
and id
is only
relevant if we have repeated observations for the same individual.
Data sets can have two different shapes: a wide shape (one row for each choice situation) or a long shape (one row for each alternative and, therefore, as many rows as there are alternatives for each choice situation).
mlogit
deals with both format. It depends on the dfidx
package
which takes as first argument a data.frame
and returns a
dfidx
object, which is a data.frame
in "long" format with a
special data frame column which contains the indexes.
Train
^[Used by @BENA:BOLD:BRAD:93 and @MEIJ:ROUW:06.] is an example
of a wide data set:
data("Train", package = "mlogit") Train$choiceid <- 1:nrow(Train) head(Train, 3)
This data set contains data about a stated preference survey in
Netherlands. Each individual has responded to several (up to 16)
scenarios. For every scenario, two train trips are proposed to the
user, with different combinations of four attributes: price
(the
price in cents of guilders), time
(travel time in minutes),
change
(the number of changes) and comfort
(the class of
comfort, 0, 1 or 2, 0 being the most comfortable class).
This "wide" format is suitable to store choice situation (or individual specific) variables because, in this case, they are stored only once in the data. Otherwise, it is cumbersome for alternative specific variables because there are as many columns for such variables that there are alternatives.
For such a wide data set, the shape
argument of dfidx
is
mandatory, as its default value is "long"
. The alternative specific
variables are indicated with the varying
argument which is a numeric
vector that indicates their position in the data frame. This argument
is then passed to stats::reshape
that coerced the original
data.frame
in "long" format. Further arguments may be passed to
reshape
. For example, as the names of the variables are of the form
price_A
, one must add sep = "_"
(the default value being
"."
). The choice
argument is also mandatory because the response
has to be transformed in a logical value in the long format. To take
the panel dimension into account, one has to add an argument id.var
which is the name of the individual index.
Tr <- dfidx(Train, shape = "wide", varying = 4:11, sep = "_", idx = list(c("choiceid", "id")), idnames = c(NA, "alt"))
Note the use of the opposite
argument for the 4 covariates: we
expect negative coefficients for all of them, taking the opposite of
the covariates will lead to expected positive coefficients. We next
convert price
and time
in more meaningful unities, hours and euros
(1 guilder was $2.20371$ euros):
Tr$price <- Tr$price / 100 * 2.20371 Tr$time <- Tr$time / 60
head(Tr, 3)
An idx
column is added to the data, which contains the three
relevant indexes: choiceid
is the choice situation index, alt
the
alternative index and id
is the individual index. This column can be
extracted using the idx
funtion:
head(idx(Tr), 3)
ModeCanada
,^[Used in particular by [@FORI:KOPP:93],
@BHAT:95, @KOPP:WEN:98 and @KOPP:WEN:00.] is an example of a data
set in long format. It presents the choice of individuals for a
transport mode for the Ontario-Quebec corridor:
data("ModeCanada", package = "mlogit") head(ModeCanada)
There are four transport modes (air
, train
, bus
and car
) and
most of the variable are alternative specific (cost
for monetary
cost, ivt
for in vehicle time, ovt
for out of vehicle time, freq
for frequency). The only choice situation specific variables are
dist
(the distance of the trip), income
(household income),
urban
(a dummy for trips which have a large city at the origin or
the destination) and noalt
the number of available alternatives. The
advantage of this shape is that there are much fewer columns than in
the wide format, the caveat being that values of dist
, income
and
urban
are repeated four times.
For data in "long" format, the shape
and the choice
arguments are
no more mandatory.
To replicate published results later in the text, we'll use only a
subset of the choice situations, namely those for which the 4
alternatives are available. This can be done using the subset
function with the subset
argument set to noalt == 4
while
estimating the model. This can also be done within dfidx
, using the
subset
argument.
The information about the structure of the data can be explicitly
indicated using choice situations and alternative indexes
(respectively case
and alt
in this data set) or, in part, guessed
by the dfidx
function. Here, after subsetting, we have 2779 choice
situations with 4 alternatives, and the rows are ordered first by
choice situation and then by alternative (train
, air
, bus
and
car
in this order).
The first way to read correctly this data frame is to ignore
completely the two index variables. In this case, the only
supplementary argument to provide is the alt.levels
argument which
is a character vector that contains the name of the alternatives in
their order of appearance:
MC <- dfidx(ModeCanada, subset = noalt == 4, alt.levels = c("train", "air", "bus", "car"))
Note that this can only be used if the data set is "balanced", which
means than the same set of alternatives is available for all choice
situations. It is also possible to provide an argument alt.var
which indicates the name of the variable that contains the
alternatives
MC <- dfidx(ModeCanada, subset = noalt == 4, idx = list(NA, "alt"))
The name of the variable that contains the information about the
choice situations can be indicated using the chid.var
argument:
MC <- dfidx(ModeCanada, subset = noalt == 4, idx = "case", alt.levels = c("train", "air", "bus", "car"))
Both alternative and choice situation variable can also be provided:
MC <- dfidx(ModeCanada, subset = noalt == 4, idx = c("case", "alt"))
More simply, as the two indexes are stored in the first two columns of
the original data frame, the idx
argument can be unset:
MC <- dfidx(ModeCanada, subset = noalt == 4)
and the indexes can be kept as stand alone series if the drop.index
argument is set to FALSE
:
MC <- dfidx(ModeCanada, subset = noalt == 4, idx = c("case", "alt"), drop.index = FALSE) head(MC)
Standard formula
s are not very practical to describe random utility
models, as these models may use different sets of covariates.
Actually, working with random utility models, one has to consider at
most four sets of covariates:
The first three sets of covariates enter the observable part of the utility which can be written, alternative $j$:
$$ V_{ij}=\alpha_j + \beta x_{ij} + \nu t_j + \gamma_j z_i + \delta_j w_{ij} . $$
As the absolute value of utility is irrelevant, only utility differences are useful to modelise the choice for one alternative. For two alternatives $j$ and $k$, we obtain:
$$ V_{ij}-V_{ik}=(\alpha_j-\alpha_k) + \beta (x_{ij}-x_{ik}) + (\gamma_j-\gamma_k) z_i + (\delta_j w_{ij} - \delta_k w_{ik}) + \nu(t_j - t_k). $$
It is clear from the previous expression that coefficients of choice situation specific variables (the intercept being one of those) should be alternative specific, otherwise they would disappear in the differentiation. Moreover, only differences of these coefficients are relevant and can be identified. For example, with three alternatives 1, 2 and 3, the three coefficients $\gamma_1, \gamma_2, \gamma_3$ associated to a choice situation specific variable cannot be identified, but only two linear combinations of them. Therefore, one has to make a choice of normalization and the simplest one is just to set $\gamma_1 = 0$.
Coefficients for alternative and choice situation specific variables may (or may not) be alternative specific. For example, transport time is alternative specific, but 10 mn in public transport may not have the same impact on utility than 10 mn in a car. In this case, alternative specific coefficients are relevant. Monetary cost is also alternative specific, but in this case, one can consider than 1\$ is 1\$ whatever it is spent for the use of a car or in public transports. In this case, a generic coefficient is relevant.
The treatment of alternative specific variables don't differ much from the alternative and choice situation specific variables with a generic coefficient. However, if some of these variables are introduced, the $\nu$ parameter can only be estimated in a model without intercepts to avoid perfect multicolinearity.
Individual-related heteroscedasticity [see @SWAI:LOUV:93] can be addressed by writing the utility of choosing $j$ for individual $i$: $U_{ij}=V_{ij} + \sigma_i \epsilon_{ij}$, where $\epsilon$ has a variance that doesn't depend on $i$ and $j$ and $\sigma_i^2 = f(v_i)$ is a parametric function of some individual-specific covariates. Note that this specification induce choice situation heteroscedasticity, also denoted scale heterogeneity.^[This kind of heteroscedasticity shouldn't be confused with alternative heteroscedasticity ($\sigma^2_j \neq \sigma^2_k$) which is introduced in the heteroskedastic logit model described in vignette relaxing the iid hypothesis]. As the overall scale of utility is irrelevant, the utility can also be writen as: $U_{ij}^* = U_{ij} / \sigma_i = V_{ij}/\sigma_i + \epsilon_{ij}$, i.e., with homoscedastic errors. if $V_{ij}$ is a linear combination of covariates, the associated coefficients are then divided by $\sigma_i$.
A logit model with only choice situation specific variables is sometimes called a multinomial logit model, one with only alternative specific variables a conditional logit model and one with both kind of variables a mixed logit model. This is seriously misleading: conditional logit model is also a logit model for longitudinal data in the statistical literature and mixed logit is one of the names of a logit model with random parameters. Therefore, in what follows, we'll use the name multinomial logit model for the model we've just described whatever the nature of the explanatory variables used.
mlogit
package provides objects of class mFormula
which are built
upon Formula
objects provided by the Formula
package.^[See
[@ZEIL:CROIS:10] for a description of the Formula
package.] The
Formula
package provides richer formula
s, which accept multiple
responses (a feature not used here) and multiple set of covariates. It
has in particular specific model.frame
and model.matrix
methods
which can be used with one or several sets of covariates.
To illustrate the use of mFormula
objects, we use again the
ModeCanada
data set and consider three sets of covariates that will
be indicated in a three-part formula, which refers to the first three
items of the four points list at start of this section.
cost
(monetary cost) is an alternative specific covariate
with a generic coefficient (part 1),income
and urban
are choice situation specific
covariates (part 2),ivt
(in vehicle travel time) is alternative specific and
alternative specific coefficients are expected (part 3).library("Formula") f <- Formula(choice ~ cost | income + urban | ivt)
Some parts of the formula may be omitted when there is no
ambiguity. For example, the following sets of formula
s are
identical:
f2 <- Formula(choice ~ cost + ivt | income + urban) f2 <- Formula(choice ~ cost + ivt | income + urban | 0)
f3 <- Formula(choice ~ 0 | income | 0) f3 <- Formula(choice ~ 0 | income)
f4 <- Formula(choice ~ cost + ivt) f4 <- Formula(choice ~ cost + ivt | 1) f4 <- Formula(choice ~ cost + ivt | 1 | 0)
By default, an intercept is added to the model, it can be removed by
using + 0
or - 1
in the second part.
f5 <- Formula(choice ~ cost | income + 0 | ivt) f5 <- Formula(choice ~ cost | income - 1 | ivt)
model.frame
and model.matrix
methods are provided for mFormula
objects. The latter is of particular interest, as illustrated in the
following example:
f <- Formula(choice ~ cost | income | ivt) mf <- model.frame(MC, f) head(model.matrix(mf), 4)
The model matrix contains $J-1$ columns for every choice situation specific
variables (income
and the intercept), which means that the
coefficient associated to the first alternative (air
) is set to
0. It contains only one column for cost
because we want a generic
coefficient for this variable. It contains $J$ columns for ivt
,
because it is an alternative specific variable for which we want
alternative specific coefficients.
As for all models estimated by maximum likelihood, three testing
procedures may be applied to test hypothesis about models fitted using
mlogit
. The set of hypothesis tested defines two models: the
unconstrained model that doesn't take these hypothesis into account
and the constrained model that impose these hypothesis.
This in turns define three principles of tests: the Wald test, based only on the unconstrained model, the Lagrange multiplier test (or score test), based only on the constrained model and the likelihood ratio test, based on the comparison of both models.
Two of these three tests are implemented in the lmtest
package
[@ZEIL:HOTH:02]: waldtest
and lrtest
. The Wald test is also implemented
as linearHypothesis
in package car
[@FOX:WEIS:10], with a fairly
different syntax. We provide special methods of waldtest
and
lrtest
for mlogit
objects and we also provide a function for
the Lagrange multiplier (or score) test called scoretest
.
We'll see later that the score test is especially useful for mlogit
objects when one is interested in extending the basic multinomial
logit model because, in this case, the unconstrained model may be
difficult to estimate. For the presentation of further tests, we
provide a convenient statpval
function which extract the statistic
and the p-value from the objects returned by the testing function,
which can be either of class anova
or htest
.
statpval <- function(x){ if (inherits(x, "anova")) result <- as.matrix(x)[2, c("Chisq", "Pr(>Chisq)")] if (inherits(x, "htest")) result <- c(x$statistic, x$p.value) names(result) <- c("stat", "p-value") round(result, 3) }
Any scripts or data that you put into this service are public.
Add the following code to your website.
For more information on customizing the embed code, read Embedding Snippets.