3. Random utility model and the multinomial logit model

knitr::opts_chunk$set(echo = TRUE, message = FALSE, warning = FALSE, widtht = 65)
options(width = 65)

Random utility model

The utility for alternative $l$ is written as: $U_l=V_l+\epsilon_l$ where $V_l$ is a function of some observable covariates and unknown parameters to be estimated, and $\epsilon_l$ is a random deviate which contains all the unobserved determinants of the utility. Alternative $l$ is therefore chosen if $\epsilon_j < (V_l-V_j)+\epsilon_l \;\forall\;j\neq l$ and the probability of choosing this alternative is then:

$$ \mbox{P}(\epsilon_1 < V_l-V_1+\epsilon_l, \epsilon_2 < V_l-V_2+\epsilon_l, ..., \epsilon_J < V_l-V_J+\epsilon_l). $$

Denoting $F_{-l}$ the cumulative density function of all the $\epsilon$s except $\epsilon_l$, this probability is:

\begin{equation} (\mbox{P}l \mid \epsilon_l)= F{-l}(V_l-V_1+\epsilon_l, ..., V_l-V_J+\epsilon_l). \end{equation}

Note that this probability is conditional on the value of $\epsilon_l$. The unconditional probability (which depends only on $\beta$ and on the value of the observed explanatory variables) is obtained by integrating out the conditional probability using the marginal density of $\epsilon_l$, denoted $f_l$:

\begin{equation} \mbox{P}l=\int F{-l}(V_l-V_1+\epsilon_l, ...,V_l-V_J)+\epsilon_l)f_l(\epsilon_l) d\epsilon_l. \end{equation}

The conditional probability is an integral of dimension $J-1$ and the computation of the unconditional probability adds on more dimension of integration.

The distribution of the error terms

The multinomial logit model [@MCFAD:74] is a special case of the model developed in the previous section. It is based on three hypothesis.

The first hypothesis is the independence of the errors. In this case, the univariate distribution of the errors can be used, which leads to the following conditional and unconditional probabilities:

\begin{equation} (\mbox{P}l \mid \epsilon_l)=\prod{j\neq l}F_j(V_l-V_j+\epsilon_l) \mbox{ and } \mbox{P}l =\int \prod{j\neq l}F_j(V_l-V_j+\epsilon_l) \; f_l(\epsilon_l) \;d\epsilon_l, \end{equation}

which means that the conditional probability is the product of $J-1$ univariate cumulative density functions and the evaluation of only a one-dimensional integral is required to compute the unconditional probability.

The second hypothesis is that each $\epsilon$ follows a Gumbel distribution, whose density and probability functions are respectively:

\begin{equation} f(z)=\frac{1}{\theta}e^{-\frac{z-\mu}{\theta}} e^{-e^{-\frac{z-\mu}{\theta}}} \mbox{ and } F(z)=\int_{-\infty}^{z} f(t) dt=e^{-e^{-\frac{z-\mu}{\theta}}}, \end{equation}

where $\mu$ is the location parameter and $\theta$ the scale parameter. The first two moments of the Gumbel distribution are $\mbox{E}(z)=\mu+\theta \gamma$, where $\gamma$ is the Euler-Mascheroni constant ($\approx 0.577$) and $\mbox{V}(z)=\frac{\pi^2}{6}\theta^2$. The mean of $\epsilon_j$ is not identified if $V_j$ contains an intercept. We can then, without loss of generality suppose that $\mu_j=0, \; \forall j$. Moreover, the overall scale of utility is not identified. Therefore, only $J-1$ scale parameters may be identified, and a natural choice of normalization is to impose that one of the $\theta_j$ is equal to 1.

The last hypothesis is that the errors are identically distributed. As the location parameter is not identified for any error term, this hypothesis is essentially an homoscedasticity hypothesis, which means that the scale parameter of the Gumbel distribution is the same for all the alternatives. As one of them has been previously set to 1, we can therefore suppose that, without loss of generality, $\theta_j = 1, \;\forall j \in 1... J$. The conditional and unconditional probabilities then further simplify to:

\begin{equation} (\mbox{P}l \mid \epsilon_l)%=\prod{j\neq l}F(V_l-V_j+\epsilon_l) =\prod_{j\neq l}e^{-e^{-(V_l-Vj+\epsilon_l)}} \mbox{ and } \mbox{P}l =\int{-\infty}^{+\infty}\prod_{j\neq l}e^{-e^{-(V_l-Vj+t)}}e^{-t}e^{-e^{-t}}dt. \end{equation}

The probabilities have then very simple, closed forms, which correspond to the logit transformation of the deterministic part of the utility.

\begin{equation} P_l=\frac{e^{V_l}}{\sum_{j=1}^J e^{V_j}}. \end{equation}

IIA property

If we consider the probabilities of choice for two alternatives $l$ and $m$, we have $P_l=\frac{e^{V_l}}{\sum_j e^{V_j}}$ and $P_m=\frac{e^{V_m}}{\sum_j e^{V_j}}$. The ratio of these two probabilities is:

$$ \frac{P_l}{P_m}=\frac{e^{V_l}}{e^{V_m}}=e^{V_l-V_m}. $$

This probability ratio for the two alternatives depends only on the characteristics of these two alternatives and not on those of other alternatives. This is called the IIA property (for independence of irrelevant alternatives). IIA relies on the hypothesis that the errors are identical and independent. It is not a problem by itself and may even be considered as a useful feature for a well specified model. However, this hypothesis may be in practice violated, especially if some important variables are omitted.

Interpretation

In a linear model, the coefficients are the marginal effects of the explanatory variables on the explained variable. This is not the case for the multinomial logit model. However, meaningful results can be obtained using relevant transformations of the coefficients.

Marginal effects

The marginal effects are the derivatives of the probabilities with respect to the covariates, which can be be choice situation-specific ($z_i$) or alternative specific ($x_{ij}$):

$$ \begin{array}{rcl} \displaystyle \frac{\partial P_{il}}{\partial z_{i}}&=&P_{il}\left(\beta_l-\sum_j P_{ij}\beta_j\right) \ \displaystyle \frac{\partial P_{il}}{\partial x_{il}}&=&\gamma P_{il}(1-P_{il})\ \displaystyle \frac{\partial P_{il}}{\partial x_{ik}}&=&-\gamma P_{il}P_{ik}. \end{array} $$

Note that the last equation can be rewritten: $\frac{\mbox{d} P_{il} / P_{il}}{\mbox{d}x_{ik}} = -\gamma P_{ik}$. Therefore, when a characteristic of alternative $k$ changes, the relative change of the probabilities for every alternatives except $k$ are the same, which is a consequence of the IIA property.

Marginal rates of substitution

Coefficients are marginal utilities, which cannot be interpreted. However, ratios of coefficients are marginal rates of substitution. For example, if the observable part of utility is: $V=\beta_o +\beta_1 x_1 +\beta x_2 + \beta x_3$, join variations of $x_1$ and $x_2$ which ensure the same level of utility are such that: $dV=\beta_1 dx_1+\beta_2 dx_2=0$ so that:

$$ - \frac{dx_2}{dx_1}\mid_{dV = 0} = \frac{\beta_1}{\beta_2}. $$

For example, if $x_2$ is transport cost (in \$), $x_1$ transport time (in hours), $\beta_1 = 1.5$ and $\beta_2=0.2$, $\frac{\beta_1}{\beta_2}=30$ is the marginal rate of substitution of time in terms of \$ and the value of 30 means that to reduce the travel time of one hour, the individual is willing to pay at most 30\$ more. Stated more simply, time value is 30\$ per hour.

Consumer's surplus

Consumer's surplus has a very simple expression for multinomial logit models, which was first derived by @SMAL:ROSE:81. The level of utility attained by an individual is $U_j=V_j+\epsilon_j$, $j$ being the chosen alternative. The expected utility, from the searcher's point of view is then: $\mbox{E}(\max_j U_j)$, where the expectation is taken over the values of all the error terms. Its expression is simply, up to an additive unknown constant, the log of the denominator of the logit probabilities, often called the "log-sum":

$$ \mbox{E}(U)=\ln \sum_{j=1}^Je^{V_j}+C. $$

If the marginal utility of income ($\alpha$) is known and constant, the expected surplus is simply $\frac{\mbox{E}(U)}{\alpha}$.

Application

Random utility models are fitted using the mlogit function. Basically, only two arguments are mandatory, formula and data, if an dfidx object (and not an ordinary data.frame) is provided.

ModeCanada

We first use the ModeCanada data set, which was already coerced to a dfidx object (called MC) in the previous section. The same model can then be estimated using as data argument this dfidx object:

library("mlogit")
data("ModeCanada", package = "mlogit")
MC <- dfidx(ModeCanada, subset = noalt == 4)
ml.MC1 <- mlogit(choice ~ cost + freq + ovt | income | ivt, MC)

or a data.frame. In this latter case, further arguments that will be passed to dfidx should be indicated:

ml.MC1b <- mlogit(choice ~ cost + freq + ovt | income | ivt, ModeCanada,
subset = noalt == 4, idx = c("case", "alt"))

mlogit provides two further useful arguments:

We estimate the model on the subset of three alternatives (we exclude bus whose market share is negligible in our sample) and we set car as the reference alternative. Moreover, we use a total transport time variable computed as the sum of the in vehicle and the out of vehicle time variables.

MC$time <- with(MC, ivt + ovt)
ml.MC1 <- mlogit(choice ~ cost + freq | income | time, MC, 
alt.subset = c("car", "train", "air"), reflevel = "car")

The main results of the model are computed and displayed using the summary method:

summary(ml.MC1)

The frequencies of the different alternatives in the sample are first indicated. Next, some information about the optimization are displayed: the Newton-Ralphson method (with analytic gradient and hessian) is used, as it is the most efficient method for this simple model for which the log-likelihood function is concave. Note that very few iterations and computing time are required to estimate this model. Then the usual table of coefficients is displayed followed by some goodness of fit measures: the value of the log-likelihood function, which is compared to the value when only intercepts are introduced, which leads to the computation of the McFadden $R^2$ and to the likelihood ratio test.

The fitted method can be used either to obtain the probability of actual choices (type = "outcome") or the probabilities for all the alternatives (type = "probabilities").

head(fitted(ml.MC1, type = "outcome"))
head(fitted(ml.MC1, type = "probabilities"), 4)

Note that the log-likelihood is the sum of the log of the fitted outcome probabilities and that, as the model contains intercepts, the average fitted probabilities for every alternative equals the market shares of the alternatives in the sample.

sum(log(fitted(ml.MC1, type = "outcome")))
logLik(ml.MC1)
apply(fitted(ml.MC1, type = "probabilities"), 2, mean)

Predictions can be made using the predict method. If no data is provided, predictions are made for the sample mean values of the covariates.

predict(ml.MC1)

Assume, for example, that we wish to predict the effect of a reduction of train transport time of 20\%. We first create a new data.frame simply by multiplying train transport time by 0.8 and then using the predict method with this new data.frame.

NMC <- MC
# YC2020/05/03 should replace everywhere index() by idx()
NMC[idx(NMC)$alt == "train", "time"] <- 0.8 *
NMC[idx(NMC)$alt == "train", "time"]
Oprob <- fitted(ml.MC1, type = "probabilities")
Nprob <- predict(ml.MC1, newdata = NMC)
rbind(old = apply(Oprob, 2, mean), new = apply(Nprob, 2, mean))

If, for the first individuals in the sample, we compute the ratio of the probabilities of the air and the car mode, we obtain:

head(Nprob[, "air"] / Nprob[, "car"])
head(Oprob[, "air"] / Oprob[, "car"])

which is an illustration of the IIA property. If train time changes, it changes the probabilities of choosing air and car, but not their ratio.

We next compute the surplus for individuals of the sample induced by train time reduction. This requires the computation of the log-sum term (also called inclusive value or inclusive utility) for every choice situation, which is:

$$ \mbox{iv}i = \ln \sum{j = 1} ^ J e^{\beta^\top x_{ij}}. $$

For this purpose, we use the logsum function, which works on a vector of coefficients and a model.matrix. The basic use of logsum consists on providing as unique argument (called coef) a mlogit object. In this case, the model.matrix and the coef are extracted from the same model.

ivbefore <- logsum(ml.MC1)

To compute the log-sum after train time reduction, we must provide a model.matrix which is not the one corresponding to the fitted model. This can be done using the X argument which is a matrix or an object from which a model.matrix can be extracted. This can also be done by filling the data argument (a data.frame or an object from which a data.frame can be extracted using a model.frame method), and eventually the formula argument (a formula or an object for which the formula method can be applied). If no formula is provided but if data is a dfidx object, the formula is extracted from it.

ivafter <- logsum(ml.MC1, data = NMC)

Surplus variation is then computed as the difference of the log-sums divided by the opposite of the cost coefficient which can be interpreted as the marginal utility of income:

surplus <- - (ivafter - ivbefore) / coef(ml.MC1)["cost"]
summary(surplus)

Consumer's surplus variation range from 0.6 to 31 Canadian \$, with a median value of about 4\$.

Marginal effects are computed using the effects method. By default, they are computed at the sample mean, but a data argument can be provided. The variation of the probability and of the covariate can be either absolute or relative. This is indicated with the type argument which is a combination of two a (as absolute) and r (as relative) characters. For example, type = "ar" means that what is measured is an absolute variation of the probability for a relative variation of the covariate.

effects(ml.MC1, covariate = "income", type = "ar")

The results indicate that, for a 100\% increase of income, the probability of choosing air increases by 33 points of percentage, as the probabilities of choosing car and train decrease by 18 and 15 points of percentage.

For an alternative specific covariate, a matrix of marginal effects is displayed.

effects(ml.MC1, covariate = "cost", type = "rr")

The cell in the $l^{\mbox{th}}$ row and the $c^{\mbox{th}}$ column indicates the change of the probability of choosing alternative $c$ when the cost of alternative $l$ changes. As type = "rr", elasticities are computed. For example, a 10\% change of train cost increases the probabilities of choosing car and air by 3.36\%. Note that the relative changes of the probabilities of choosing one of these two modes are equal, which is a consequence of the IIA property.

Finally, in order to compute travel time valuation, we divide the coefficients of travel times (in minutes) by the coefficient of monetary cost (in \$).

coef(ml.MC1)[grep("time", names(coef(ml.MC1)))] /
    coef(ml.MC1)["cost"] * 60 

The value of travel time ranges from 23 for train to 37 Canadian \$ per hour for plane.

NOx

The second example is a data set used by @FOWL:10, called NOx. She analyzed the effect of an emissions trading program (the NOx budget program which seeks to reduce the emission of nitrogen oxides) on the behavior of producers. More precisely, coal electricity plant managers may adopt one out of fifteen different technologies in order to comply to the emissions defined by the program. Some of them require high investment (the capital cost is kcost) and are very efficient to reduce emissions, some other require much less investment but are less efficient and the operating cost (denoted vcost) is then higher, especially because pollution permits must be purchased to offset emissions exceeding their allocation.

The focus of the paper is on the effects of the regulatory environment on manager's behavior. Some firms are deregulated, whereas other are either regulated or public. Rate of returns is applied for regulated firms, which means that they perceive a "fair" rate of return on their investment. Public firms also enjoy significant cost of capital advantages. Therefore, the main hypothesis of the paper is that public and regulated firms will adopt much more capitalistic intensive technologies than deregulated and public ones, which means that the coefficient of capital cost should take a higher negative value for deregulated firms. Capital cost is interacted with the age of the plant (measured as a deviation from the sample mean age), as firms should weight capital costs more heavily for older plants, as they have less time to recover these costs.

Multinomial logit models are estimated for the three subsamples defined by the regulatory environment. The 15 technologies are not available for every plants, the sample is therefore restricted to available technologies, using the available covariate. Three technology dummies are introduced: post for post-combustion polution control technology, cm for combustion modification technology and lnb for low NOx burners technology.

A last model is estimated for the whole sample, but the parameters are allowed to be proportional to each other. The scedasticity function is described in the fourth part of the formula, it contains here only one covariate, env. Note also that for the last model, the author introduced a specific capital cost coefficient for deregulated firms.^[Note the use of the method argument, set to bhhh. mlogit use its own optimisation functions, but borrows its syntax from package maxLik [@MAXLIK:10]. The default method is bfgs, except for the basic model, for which it is nr. As the default algorithm failed to converged, we use here bhhh.]

data("NOx", package = "mlogit")
NOx$kdereg <- with(NOx, kcost * (env == "deregulated"))
NOxml <- dfidx(NOx, idx = list(c("chid", "id"), "alt"))
ml.pub <- mlogit(choice ~ post + cm + lnb + vcost + kcost + kcost:age |
- 1, subset = available & env == "public", data = NOxml)
ml.reg <- update(ml.pub, subset = available & env == "regulated")
ml.dereg <- update(ml.pub, subset = available & env == "deregulated")
ml.pool <- ml.dereg
# YC gestion de la quatrième partie
ml.pool <- mlogit(choice ~ post + cm + lnb + vcost + kcost + kcost:age +
kdereg | - 1 | 0 | env, subset = available == 1, data = NOxml,
method = "bhhh")
library("texreg")
htmlreg(list(Public = ml.pub, Deregulated = ml.dereg, Regulated = ml.reg,
             Pooled = ml.pool), caption = "Environmental compliance choices.",
        omit.coef = "(post)|(cm)|(lnb)", float.pos = "hbt", label = "tab:nox")

Results are presented in the preceeding table, using the texreg package [@LEIF:13]. Coefficients are very different on the sub-samples defined by the regulatory environment. Note in particular that the capital cost coefficient is positive and insignificant for public and regulated firms, as it is significantly negative for deregulated firms. Errors seems to have significant larger variance for deregulated firms and lower ones for public firms compared to regulated firms. The hypothesis that the coefficients (except the kcost one) are identical up to a multiplicative scalar can be performed using a likelihood ratio test:

stat <- 2 * (logLik(ml.dereg) + logLik(ml.reg) +
             logLik(ml.pub) - logLik(ml.pool))
stat
pchisq(stat, df = 9, lower.tail = FALSE)

The hypothesis is strongly rejected.

Bibliography



Try the mlogit package in your browser

Any scripts or data that you put into this service are public.

mlogit documentation built on Oct. 23, 2020, 5:29 p.m.